Paul Krugman’s Austrian Fascination|William L. Anderson

[]Paul Krugman appears to have an extremely unhealthy fixation with Austrian economics and particularly the school’s theory of business cycle. More than 20 years ago, he attacked it (wrongly calling it a “Hangover Theory” and attempting to make a morality play out of it), claiming it had the credibility of the “phlogiston theory of fire.”

[]Not remarkably, he got the theory wrong then but has decided to dig that hole of willful ignorance even deeper with a current attack in the New York City Times. Like a lot of Krugman posts, it has more economic fallacies than one can unmask in a short post, so I will stick with one point: Krugman’s belief that inflation is a cure-all to economic crises which anyone who opposes it does so out of ignorance at best and malevolence at worst.

[]For many years, Krugman has touted inflation as an economic solution in the way that some have pushed Ivermectin as a remedy for covid-19, although I think that Ivermectin may be the much better bet. (I am making an analogy, not a medical statement, so if you send me a mad e-mail about Ivermectin, I will erase the message without reading it.) My bigger point is that Krugman is trying to different himself from the Austrians by promoting inflation, something the Austrians can not and will not support– and for great factor.

[]In normal fashion, Krugman focuses upon a misnaming of the Frankfurt school by Mark Levin of Fox News as “proof” that Austrian economics is false:

[]It’s questionable the number of these self-proclaimed “Austrians” really knew what they were endorsing. In general, when right-wingers discuss intellectual history, you want to fire up your fact-checking. For example, Mark Levin of Fox News has a very popular book claiming not simply that the current American left remains in the thrall of European Marxists but more particularly that they’re followers of Herbert Marcuse and the Frankfurt School– except that he keeps calling it the “Franklin School.”

[]The study of logic calls this a non sequitur in which he takes someone who would not be called an Austrian economic expert under any scenarios and then declares that Levin’s misnaming of the Frankfurt school shows Austrians are not to be taken seriously. (Perhaps this is New York Times reasoning.)

[]After opening with a sensible fallacy, Krugman goes on to misrepresent the Austrian position on the reasons for the Great Anxiety (and why it lasted through the 1930s) and make false claims about the Austrian variation of the “debate” in between Austrians and Keynesians:

[]And the idea that there was a titanic intellectual fight in the 1930s in between Hayek and John Maynard Keynes is generally fan fiction; Hayek’s views on the Great Anxiety didn’t get much intellectual traction at the time, and his fame came later on, with the publication of his 1944 political system “The Road to Serfdom.”

[]However, there was a recognizable Austrian analysis of the Depression, shared by Hayek and other economic experts, consisting of Joseph Schumpeter. Where Keynes argued that the Anxiety was triggered by a general shortage in need, Hayek and Schumpeter argued that we were looking at the inevitable troubles of getting used to the aftermath of a boom. In their view, extreme optimism had led to the allocation of excessive labor and other resources to the production of financial investment goods, and an anxiety was just the economy’s method of getting those resources back where they belonged.

[]I am uninformed of any Austrian economics literature that claims there was a “titanic fight” between John Maynard Keynes and F.A. Hayek. In truth, Austrians agree that while there was some interest in the Austrian organization cycle theory in the early 1930s, it rapidly was eclipsed, at first with the flurry of New Offer legislation in 1933 and later on with the publication of Keynes’s General Theory. None of the best-known Austrian economists, from Ludwig von Mises to Murray Rothbard to any of the modern-day Austrians, ever has made the claim that Krugman credits to them.

[]Then there is the real Austrian analysis itself. Krugman misrepresented it in his “Hangover Theory” article, so we ought to not be surprised that he does it once again. Initially, and crucial, Austrians do not look at “excessive optimism” as a reason for anything, not to mention an unsustainable boom. Instead, they aim to the actions of monetary authorities that hold down interest rates at below-market levels, a practice that results in malinvestment in long-lasting capital products, financial investments that ultimately are not sustained by the direction of consumer costs and total savings from people. In the short run, such policies result in a boom that is supported in large part by obtained cash, and if there is “extreme optimism,” it comes from the outcomes of misguided policies.

[]Krugman’s next declaration demonstrates his misunderstanding of the Austrian theory and also his shortsightedness about what takes place in a boom:

[]This view had rational issues: If transferring resources outof financial investment items causes mass unemployment, why didn’t the exact same thing take place when resources were being transferred in and away from other markets? It was likewise clearly at odds with experience: During the Anxiety and, for that matter [,] after the 2008 crisis, there was excess capability and unemployment in almost every market– not slack in some and shortages in others.

[]Krugman just is incorrect here. In short, while Austrians mention that the artificially decreased rate of interest cause company owner to broaden lines of production that eventually will show unsustainable, the point they make is that consumer costs patterns show that common financial price signals are not showing that consumers now are avoiding present intake and increasing their savings. Instead, consumers continue to spend in the same spending/saving relationships as before, and while the structures of wage incentives are such that salaries increase in the capital products markets, those salaries increase in order to attract workers to leave the consumer goods work and migrate to capital products. (Roger Fort in Time and Money spells this point out in a lot more information and far more lucidly than I can provide it here.)

[]To put it simply, contra Krugman, the reason we don’t see patterns of joblessness is since there is no slack in durable goods sales, so employees in those industries are not being laid off. Likewise, workers in capital products are taking pleasure in higher incomes, but they are not saving their pay, or a minimum of not saving it in percentage to what is needed in order to keep the investments in capital goods sustainable. Rather, like others in the economy, they are buying consumer goods.

[]This is not a trivial point, for much of Krugman’s argument hinges around his claim that given that we don’t see patterns of mass employment in a boom, the Austrian theory can not perhaps discuss mass work during the bust. Moreover, Krugman’s entire economic world view is based upon his belief that economic crises are caused by decreases in “aggregate need,” so booms are preferable because they are sparked by such demand. When a bust occurs, he argues, federal government needs to increase its own spending in order to try to recuperate the boom conditions.

[]What Krugman stops working to understand is that the conditions of a credit-induced boom are far different than a circumstance in which consumers begin to save more for the future, hence making funds available for long-lasting capital growth. In the latter scenario, factors would be bid far from the production and sale of consumption goods in an organized manner, with incomes in the capital items industries being greater(given that there is increasing need for such items) than they are in the creation and sale of consumer goods, so the labor migration would not be a problem.

[]In a boom, however, there is no decreased need for consumer goods and matching demand boost in capital products industries. Instead, there is increased demand for capital goods and increased demand for usage products, something that would not occur if the boom were fed by savings instead of government-sponsored credit. It is clear that Krugman does not understand this point, and why ought to he, considered that all of his economic writings on booms and slumps are based upon the presumption that factors of production are homogeneous rather of being heterogeneous, as they remain in Austrian theory?

[]This essential point carries into Krugman’s Keynesian prescription for reducing joblessness following a bust. He composes:

[]Hayek and (Joseph) Schumpeter were adamantly against any attempt to eliminate the Great Depression with monetary and fiscal stimulus. Hayek decriedthe use of “synthetic stimulants,” insisting that we should instead “leave it to time to effect an irreversible treatment by the sluggish procedure of adapting the structure of production.” Schumpeter warned that”any revival which is simply due to artificial stimulus leaves part of the work of depressions undone.”

[]However these conclusions didn’t follow even if you accepted their incorrect analysis of what the Anxiety was all about. Why should the requirement to move employees out of a sector cause unemployment? Why shouldn’t it simply lead to lower wages?

[]The answer in practice is downward small wage rigidity: Employers are actually reluctant to cut salaries, due to the fact that of the impacts on employee spirits. Here’s the distribution of wage changes in 2009– 10, from the connected paper:

[]Distribution of wage changes, 2009– 10. Credit … Fallick et al []

[]The big spike at no represents great deals of employers who had an abundance of task candidates however didn’t want to cut earnings, so they just left them unchanged.

[]Nevertheless, if wages can’t fall in the sector that requires to shrink, why can’t they increase in the sector that needs to broaden? Sure, it would cause a short-lived increase in inflation– however that would be OK. (emphasis mine)

[]Krugman believes (as did Keynes) that rather of motivating salaries to fall as labor demand decreases in a bust, governments ought to inflate the currency in order to decrease the real wage even as it is enhancing the small wage. Keynes argued in The General Theory that utilizing inflation to decrease real salaries not just minimizes the accompanying strife when employees see their earnings cut, however likewise would not lead to a loss of “aggregate demand,” hence transcending both financially and morally.

[]Both Krugman and Keynes also argue that allowing salaries to fall would lower “aggregate demand” and would lead to a downward spiral in production and joblessness, resulting in what Henry Hazlitt in The Failure of the New Economics referred to as a perverse stability, all fed by a liquidity trap. (Hazlitt was explaining the Keynesian position, not endorsing that perspective.) Hence, Krugman’s recommendation of what he calls “transitory inflation” is based upon a belief that inflation is the only viable choice to ending an economic downturn.

[]One may be able to make this argument if elements of production were homogeneous and it didn’t matter where one spent cash– simply as long as it was invested. Nevertheless, if elements are heterogeneous, then Krugman’s Keynesian inflation technique is very unpleasant, for it would lead to financial dislocations that only would be worsened by subsequent rounds of inflation by monetary authorities.

[]This point is essential to comprehending federal government financial intervention. In a rate system, we value items relative both to money and to each other. As the supply of cash increases (or reduces), not just does the worth of individual aspects change relative to cash, but the worth of elements changes relative to other factors.

[]Krugman uses the example of what took place in the pandemic, believing that the circumstance he explains discredits the Austrian school when, in reality, it damages Krugman’s analysis. Composes Krugman:

[]Although we aren’t hearing much about Austrian economics nowadays, the pandemic actually did produce an Austrian-style reallocation shock, with demand for some things surging while need for other things slumped. You can see this even at a macro level: There was a huge increase in purchases of long lasting products even as services struggled. (Believe people buying stationary bikes because they can’t go to the health club. Hey, I did.)

[]When authorities stated some markets “vital” while closing “unnecessary” ones, they likewise altered the relative value of elements of production, and Krugman accurately describes this in the preceding paragraph. Yet, even with a genuine, live example prior to him that he acknowledges, Krugman then goes on to require a policy “prescription” that is based upon the assumption that aspects are homogeneous.

[]Krugman seems to be able to accept that relationships between factors can be changed when authorities freely prefer some industries over others, however he can decline the fact that when governments intervene in markets both monetarily and fiscally the exact same kind of thing can take place. Rather, he quickly reverts to the thinking that if federal governments pump up, then inflation brings back a low-unemployment balance to the economy.

[]In his 1998 short article in Slate, Krugman argues that the Austrian position on business cycles seems to be borne more out of a perverted sense of morality than anything economic. In his view, the Austrians resemble the stern imaginary teacher Ichabod Crane, who sternly keeps his students in line. Rather of seeking the total good of the economy, Austrians (according to Krugman) believe that a boom is a sort of bacchanalia that must be penalized by an economic downturn, hence blinding them to the need to continue a boom once individuals inexplicably stop spending money and grind the economy to a stop.

[]Yet an economy can not have heterogeneous aspects of production at one moment, then relatively transform them into homogeneous elements when the government switches on the inflation spigots. That merely is not rational, and while Krugman routinely utilizes rational misconceptions in order to belabor his points, one presumes that even he can see the mistake in his own conflicting analysis. However, however, perhaps not.

About the author

Click here to add a comment

Leave a comment: